Ó2009ElsevierLtd.Allrightsreserved
0305-750X/$-seefrontmatter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2009.11.009
HasMercantilismReducedUrbanPovertyinSSA?Perception
´andBamakoofBoom,Bust,andtheChina–AfricaTradeinLome
MICHALLYONS
LondonSouthBankUniversity,London,UK
and
ALISONBROWN*UniversityofCardiff,UK
Summary.—ThispaperaddressestheimmediateimpactsoftheChina–AfricatradeonAfrica’sinformaltradersanditslongertermimpactonurbanpoverty,basedonacomparisonofthemajorcitiesoftwoWestAfricancountriesanddrawingonsemi-structuredinter-viewswithtradersandonschedule-basedinterviewswithkeyinformantsingovernment,businessandtheinformaltradesector.ThefindingsarethattheincreaseinimportsfromChinainitiallybroadenedaccesstotradingforthepoor,creatingshort-termimprovementsinlivelihoods,butcompetitionisdrivingdownprofitmargins,andrestrictingthetradetoasurvivalmechanismformanytoday.Thusithasprovidedlimitedlong-termpotentialasaneconomicplatformfornationaldevelopmentandpovertyreduction.ThefindingsarediscussedintermsofstructurationtheoryandintermsofalternativeconceptualizationsofinformaltradeinAfrica.Ó2009ElsevierLtd.Allrightsreserved.
Keywords—sub-SaharanAfrica,togo,mali,informaleconomy,China–Africa
1.INTRODUCTION
Trade,globalization,andadjustmentpolicieshavepro-foundimpactsontheAfricanurbanpoorworkingintheinformaleconomy(Carr&Chen,2002;Cohen,2004).Thedeclineinformalemploymentinadministrationandmanu-facturing,whichfollowedtheoilpriceshocksofthe1970sandstructuraladjustmentinthe1980s,hasresultedinasig-nificantincreaseininformalwork(Bryceson&Potts,2006,p.44).GiventhehistoricalimportanceoftradeinmanyAfricancommunities,amajorfocusforthisgrowthhasbeenincommerce,withstreettradenoweconomicallysignificant,andakeysourceofnewjobsfortheurbanpoor(Chen&Carr,2004;Simone,2004,p.25;Skinner,2008,pp.7–9),althoughpoliticallymotivatedevictionsremainaconstantthreat(Hansen,2004,p.77).Asstreettradehasincreasedinscale,itscharacterhaschanged.Streettradersarelongerpredominantlyanoutletforlocalproduce.Instead,manytradersarelinkedtoglobalsupplynetworks.ParticularlyevidenthasbeentheincreasedsaleofChinese-manufacturedimportsinurbanmarketsoverthelast5–10years(Lyons,Brown,&Li,2008).
ThispaperaddressestheimmediateimpactsoftheChina–AfricatradeonAfrica’sinformaltradersanditslongertermimpactonurbanpoverty,basedonacomparisonofthemajor
´,wheretradeiscitiesoftwoWestAfricancountries:Lome
heavilyinfluencedbyTogo’sfreeport,andBamakoinland-lockedMali.
Thispapersetsoutatheoreticalframeworkfortheresearchdrawnfromstructurationtheory,exploringideasofperverseoutcomesofaggregatedactions.ItthenbrieflydiscussestherecentrapidexpansionoftheChina–Africatradeandexplores
´andBamako.Finally,itexaminesthecontextoftradeinLome
thedifferentstrategiesadoptedbytraders,andtheiroutcomesforpoverty.
771
2.THEORETICALFRAMEWORK
Giddensfamouslyarguedthatthesocialinstitutionscon-straininghumanactionaremodifiedthroughtheaggregateinfluenceoftheexerciseoflimitedchoicebyamultitudeofpeople(1984).Giddensacknowledgedthatsuchstructuralchangecanbe‘‘perverse’’or‘‘suboptimal’’indifferentways.Thiscanarisebecausetheactioncreatesanintendedeffectinisolationbutperverseeffectsifeveryonefollowsbutactorsareunawareofthispotentialcomplication(Elster,1978inGiddens,1984,p.311).Asecondinterpretationdrawsfromgametheory,arguingthatactors,thoughawareoftheconse-quencesoftheiraction,chooseasuboptimalstrategytoachievepersonalbenefitsinrelationtootherpeople.Anexam-pleisthatofacartel,whichwouldbenefitmembers,butcre-atesaprofitableoptionforsomeonewhofloutsthecartel,thusnoonejoins(Olsen,1963inGiddens,1984,p.312).TheseargumentsledGiddenstoformulatetheconceptof“structuralcontradiction”,inwhichthe“conditionsofsystemreproductiondependonstructuralproperties”whichnegatetheprinciplesonwhichtheyarebased(1984,p.314),forexamplethecapitaliststatewhich“dependsonaprocessofaccumulationwhichisbeyonditspowertoorganize”(1984,p.315).Thispaperexploresthe“unintendedconsequences”ofindividualactionsofurbaninformaltraders.
Someapproachestopovertyreductionstressthepotentialofindividual(orhousehold-level)strategiesandoutcomes.Forexample,proponentsofthesustainablelivelihoodsframe-work(Scoones,1998)areinterestedinpossibleofroutesoutofchronicpovertyandintheabilityoflargenumbersofthepoortosustaintheirlivelihoodsandsurviveinthefaceofadversetrendsandshocks.Theyarguethatbyexchangingoneform
*Finalrevisionaccepted:October21,2009.
772WORLDDEVELOPMENT
ofassetforanotherandbydevelopingalternativeassets,thepoorcouldexercisesufficientagencytomaintainstability,orpossiblyimprovetheireconomicstatus.
Inrelationtostreettrade,researchhasshownthatsocialcapital––akeycomponentofthelivelihoodsframework––isimportantinenablinginformalindividualtradersadaptandsustaintheirlivelihoods(Kumar&Matsusaka,2004),andthatcollectivesocialcapitaloftraderscansometimesbemobilizedtomitigatetherepressivebehaviorofurbanauthoritiestowardtheiruseofpublicspace(Brown,2006,pp.183–185).Thesebodiesofworkoverlap,buthavedistinctemphases;thefirstsuggeststhatindividualscandevelopmoreeffectiveeconomicstrategiesbydrawingonthepowerofagroup,whilethesec-ondemphasizesthepotentialofgroupstoprotectaspaceforaction––physicalorpolitical––inthecity.Bothargumentsconcludethatsomeindividualsandgroupsareabletofunc-tionbetterthanotherswithinagiveneconomicandpoliticalframework.
However,someworkoninformaltraderssuggeststhatindi-vidualactivitiesmayhavesignificantaggregateeffects(Lyons&Snoxell,2005a,2005b).Forexample,Fafchamps,Gabre-Madhin,andMinten(2004)havearguedthattheaggregateoutcomeofmodifiedsocialcapitallinkshasbeentoimprovetheefficiencyofmarketingagriculturalproduce,findingsex-pandedandreinforcedbyLyonandPorter,Lyons,andPotls(2007).However,theworkoninformaltradehasnotgenerallyarguedthataggregateoutcomesofindividuallivelihooddeci-sionscanbeperverse,assuggestedbyresearchinotherliveli-hoodareas(Maclure,2006;Rodgers,2005).
Theadoptionofmarketinnovationsbyalargenumberoftradersisoneformofaggregateaction.Thishasbeendis-cussedfromastructurationperspectiveasthecreationofopportunity,inturnattractingentry,intimeresultingingrow-ingcompetition,reductioninprofitmarginsandeventualmar-ketsaturation(Bhowmick,2007;Poole,Clarke,&Clarke,2006).Thestructurationmodelalsoenablesentrepreneurialactivitiestobeinterpretedwithinmulti-layeredcontextswheretradingresponsesareseenasanegotiationbetweenbroaderandimmediateenvironments(Morawska,2004).
Ofparticularnoteistheobservationthattradersoperatingininternationalmarketsmayoftenlacksophisticationinunderstandingnewmarketsortheabilitytocopewithnewchallenges(Alexander,1997).IntheSouth,structurationanal-ysisofretailmarketshaslargelyfocusedontheintroductionofICT,inwhichsectormarketsaturationisadistantprospect(Walsham&Sahay,2006).However,thispaperisconcernedwiththeintroductionofinnovationswhichbothcompetewithlocalmanufactureandsaturatethemarket,andaskswhattheirpovertyimpacthasbeen,andwhy.
3.THECHINA–AFRICATRADE
TheincreaseofChinese-manufacturedimportstoAfricaisonefacetofChina’swideninghorizonsandburgeoningecon-omy.TheexpansionoftheChineseeconomy,almost10%perannumsince1990,owesmuchtoexports.FollowingChina’saccessiontotheWTOin2001itslabor-intensivemanufactur-inggrew.StrengthenedpoliticaltieswithdevelopingcountrieswerepromotedbyChina,bothtochallengeestablishedglobalpowerrelationsandtodevelopnewsourcesofrawmaterials(FOCAC,2008).
TherecentgrowthinChinesetradehascometorepresentacriticalgrowthareaforAfricaneconomies.During1991–2000,Africa–Chinabilateraltradegrewmorethan700%,startingfromaverysmallbase.FollowingthefirstChina–AfricaFor-
700060005000Guinea4000KenyaMali3000Tanzania2000TogoUganda1000Ghana0-100078901234567999000000009990000000011122222222Source: Direction of Trade Statistics, IMF, extracted by the authors Figure1.Balanceoftrade(importslessexports)1997–2007(US$million).uminBeijingin2000,bilateraltradegrewtomorethan$20bnoverthefouryearstotheendof2004,andhasexpandedyearonyeareversince.Africanmanufacturinghasnotincreaseditsshareofexportsduringtheperiod(Kaplinsky,McCormick,&Morris,2006).Astradehasincreased,importshaveincreas-inglyoutstrippedimportsasshownforselectedcountries(Figure1).
FortheChineseeconomy,exportstoAfricaremainrela-tivelyinsignificant––only2%ofChina’s2004exportsweretoAfrica––butforthemuchsmallerdevelopingAfricanecono-miestherapidcumulativeincreasefaroutstripsgrowthinGDP(e.g.,theselectedcountriesinFigure2).Some80%ofimportsareprocessed/manufactured,light-industrialcon-sumergoods(Goldstein,Pinaud,Reisen,&Chen,2006).Themarketsunderstudyherecanbroadlybedividedintothreecategories:shoes,clothing,andpersonalitems(suchasbags,hairextensions,andjewelry);householdgoods;mobilephonesandphoneaccessories,andelectricalitemsfromcalcu-latorstoTVs.
TheimportanddistributionofChinese-manufacturedgoodsinAfricahavebeenlargelyattributedtoexpatriateChi-nesetraders.AgrowingliteratureanalyzesthestrategiesofChinesediasporasinAfrica,forexampleinNamibiaandAn-golawhereChinesefunctionlargelyaswholesalers(Dobler,2005);CapeVerdewhereincreasingandcontinuedcompeti-tionwithintheChinesetradingcommunityhaserodedprofitsandresultedinitsvirtualcollapse(Haugen&Carling,2005);andSenegalwheresuccessinstrugglesoverspaceandmunici-palsupporthavebeencentraltothecommercialestablishmentofChinesewholesalers(Scheld,2007).Incontrast,Africanstreettradeiswidelyseenasfocusedonthedistributionoflo-calproduce,goods,andservices.
Increasingly,however,AfricansareplayinganimportantroleintheChina–Africatrade.Thus,inparallelwiththerapidgrowthofstreettrade(UNDP,2008,p.37),thestreetecon-omyhasbecomemorecommercialandinternationalinchar-acter,withmanyAfricantradersactingasbuyers,shippers,andwholesalersinrelativelysmall-scaleyetcomplexinterna-tionalsupplychains(Lyonsetal.,2008).
Theaimofthispaperisthustoexplorethecharacteristicsof
theurbaninformaltradingcommunityinLome
´andBamako,andtheimpactoftheChina–Africatradeonthecommunity,usingthelensofstructurationtheoryasananalyticalframe-workandseenfromtheperspectiveofmarkettraders’them-selves.Thehypothesisisthatthelarge-scaletakeupoftradinginChinese-manufacturedconsumergoodsbyurban
HASMERCANTILISMREDUCEDURBANPOVERTYINSSA?
773
403530Ghana25Kenya20Tanzania15MaliTogo105020002001200220032004200520062007Source: Extracted by the authors from IMF Direction of Trade Statistics Figure2.Balanceoftrade(importslessexports)as%ofGDP.informaltradersiserodingthemarketopportunitieswhichtheyseektoexploit.Theresearchobjectivesarethusto:
explorethecharacteristicsoftheurbanmarkettrading
communityinLome
´andBamako;exploretraders’perceptionsoftheimportanceoftheimportsectorforsmalltraders
analyzethechangingopportunitiesandconstraintsfortraders,and
analyzethecumulativeandunintendedconsequencesofcollectiveinvolvementintheChina–Africatrade.
TheresearchwasfundedbytheBritish-Academy,andtheteamhasalsoundertakenresearchonAfricanimportersbasedinGuangzhouinsouthernChina,whichisnotreportedhere.Thefocushasbeenontheperspectivesofactorsdirectlyin-volvedintheexpandingimporttradeand,astheresearchwasasmallproject,theteamhasnotyetsituatedthefindingsinawideranalysisofnationalandregionaltradepolicyandinternationalrelationswithChina.
4.CONTEXT
BothTogoandMalihavethesignificantinformalecono-miestypicalofsub-SaharanAfrica(SSA).In2007,Togo’sGNIpercapitawasestimatedatUS$360andMali’satUS$500;inMalitheinequalityrateasexpressedbytheGinicoefficientwas0.4in2001,highbyinternationalstandards(NBnoequivalentdataforTogo);and,inboth,thereisahighproportionofbelow-povertylinepopulation––60%(WB,2008).In2004theirshadoweconomieswereestimatedat40%ofofficialGDPforTogoand45%forMali,comparedtoanaverageof43%forsomefortySAAcountries;theanal-ysisusedamultiple-indicatorseconometricapproachtoesti-mateatnationalscaleunreportedincomefromtheproductionoflegalgoodsandservices(Schneider,2004).Takentogether,thesedatasuggestastrongincentiveineachcountryforthepoortoestablishsmall-scale,informalenter-prises,requiringlowstart-upcapitalandsomelivelihoodandmobilityopportunities.Theincreasingdominanceofcom-merceintheireconomies,andthereinforcementofbilaterallinkswithChinaoverthepastdecade,haveensuredrapidgrowthofChinese-manufacturedimportsasapercentageofGDP(Figure1)andalsoresultedinrelativeeasingofvisarestrictionsincomparisonwithEurope(althoughsincetherun-uptotheBeijingOlympicsinthesummerof2008visarestrictionsonAfricanvisitorstoChinahavebecome––andremain––verysevere).
Recentimportandexportfiguresdemonstratetheimpor-tanceofcommerce,indicatingashiftfrommanufacturing
andartisanalindustriestocommerce.InTogotheshifthasbeenmorerapidthaninMali.DataontradewithChinadem-onstratethatMalicapitalcitiesLome
´andTogo,andtheirmaincommercialand
andBamako,playdifferentrolesintheex-portchain.In2005Togo’stradewithChinacameto$570M,wellbelowsuchoilexportinggiantsasNigeria($2830M)butsimilartolargetradingeconomiessuchasGhana,Tanzania,andKenya;whileMali’scameto$145M.Togo’slocationonthecoastanditsfreeport,haveensuredthatimportsarefarhigherinrelationtoitseconomy(inrelationtoGDP)thaninmostoftheregion.Incontrast,Mali’sland-lockedpositionhascontributedtoitspositioningfurtheralongthedistribu-tionchain(Figure2).
Togohasbeendescribedasa‘‘failed’’state,followingitsmilitarycoupin1967andclosetofortyyearsofuninterrupteddictatorship.However,followingthedeathofPresidentGnas-sinbeEyademain2005,ithasprogressivelyadopteddemo-craticprocessesundertheleadershipofPresidentFaureGnassinbe.AbandonedbyEuropeandonorsin1993,andbytheWorldBankin2003,butinearly2008whenthefieldworktookplacethecountrywasintalkswithUNDP,theWorldBank,andotherdonors,andwasintheprocessofdevelopingaPRSP(KIinterviews).Thecountryhastakenalaissez-faire
attitudetotradethroughtheportandLome
´,andtomigra-tion.Ethnicallythecountryismixed.ThirtysevenAfricantribesarerepresentedin99%ofthepopulation(withonly1%whiteEuropeansorothers).Thepopulationisgrowingat2.8%perannum(WB,2008).
MuchoftheethnicvarietyisevidentinLome
´,withlargecommunitiesofChristians,animists,andMuslims.Neverthe-less,thepopulationofLome
´ispredominantlyEwelikesouth-ernGhanaandBenin,andthecoloniallyimposedbordersare
porous,withethnicitymoreimportantthannationality.Lome
´sitsonthemainrouteconnectingLagoswithAbidjanandservesasadistributionpointforgoodsthroughouttheWestAfricancoast.Thecityhasapopulationofaround1millionpeople,ofwhom80%arethoughttoworkintheinformaleconomy(KIinterview)althoughreliablestatisticsarerare––atthetimeoffieldworkthelastcensushadbeentaken
in1981.ThefreeportinLome
´isanimportantgatewayforim-ports,particularlytoNigeria,Niger,BurkinaFaso,Ghana,andMali,reportedlymoreattractivethanCotonouinBenin,orTemainGhana.Officialstatisticsindicatethatin2005,72%oftotaltradeatthefreeportwasimportswithof10%Lome
´ofgoods(PortAutonomedeLome
´anincrease
,2009).hasaspatialhierarchyofmarkets.Therearetwomainmarketsinwhichconsumergoodsaresold.Grand
Marche
´,aregionalcenterofthewaxedclothpredominanceofwomentraders;andHe
`trade,withadzranawe´,northeastofthecity,createdabout12yearsagowhentradersinsecond-handclotheswererelocatedfromthecitycenterenmassetoanewsitenearertheairport,whichincludestradingcommunitiesfromBenin,Nigeria,Niger,Mali,Chad,etc.Neighborhoodmarketssellfoodandsmallhouseholditems.Thereisalsoawell-establishedcommunityofsome4,000Chineseresidents,manyofwhomaretraders,reflectingbilat-eralpoliticallinksofover20yearswithAfricanseducatedinChina,andChineseconstructionfirmsbuildinggovernmentbuildings.
Maliembraceddemocracywithindependenceandhasmain-tainedfreeelectionsthroughout,butdevelopedmoreslowlyeconomicallyandisheavilydependentonworldcottonprices.Sociallyandculturallyithasremainedmorehomogenous––andconservative––thanTogo.Atthesametime,itislesswellplacedtocapitalizeonliberalizingreforms,beinglandlockedandremotefrommajortrans-shipmentpoints.
774WORLDDEVELOPMENT
Populationgrowthwasapproximately2.7%perannumin2008.Rural–urbanmigrationhasbeenamajordriverofurbangrowthinBamako,althoughmanymigrantsretainacircularmigrationpatternwhichsupplementsseasonalworkinagriculture.Inthecountryasawhole,thepopulationispredominantlycomposedofthethreelargestMendetribes(50%),particularlyBambara,withthebalancemadeupbysomefiveothertribes(WB,2008).Muslimscomprise99%ofthepopulation.LiteracylevelsaresignificantlylowerthaninTogo(46%comparedwith60%(WB,2008)).Therearevirtu-allynoforeigncommunitiesand,reportedly,itisdifficulttoestablishbusinessesinMalievenforotherWestAfricannationals(KIinterviews).
SituatedonthebanksoftheNigerRiver,Bamakohaslongbeenanimportantcenterforinlandtrade.AsMali’sadminis-trativecapital,andlargestcity,withapopulationestimatedtobe1.3min2001,nownearer1.6m,duringthelate1990sitsgrowthratewasestimatedtonearly6%––oneofthefastestur-bangrowthratesinAfrica(BNETD,2001).Povertyindicatorsweresignificant,withanestimatedonethirdofthepopulationbelownationalpovertyline,thenumbersofpeoplewithaccesstopipedwaterbeing20%andtopublicsewerage1.5%,andlit-eracyratesat18%.Anestimated64%ofpeoplewereworkinginformally(BNETD,2001).
Inbothcountries,urbanpolicytowardtradersisguidednationally.InTogo,inFebruary2007,thegovernment’smin-istryforsmall-scaleenterprisespromotedaNationalForumontheInformalSector,buttheministrywasingthe2007election(KIinterviewLome
´downgradedfollow-)andhasbeeneffec-tivelydormantsince.InMali,thedirectorategeneralofcommercehasaprojecttosupportpettytraders,althoughtheapproachfocusesonformalizationandlicensing(KIinter-viewBamako),butthishasnottranslatedintomoretolerantpolicing,whilethenationallyrecognizednegotiatingforumex-cludeshawkers.
5.METHODS
Theresearchdrewmainlyonkeyinformantinterviewswithgovernmentofficials,multilateralagencies,andcommunityleaders,andonin-depthsemi-structuredinterviewswithtrad-ersthemselves.Traderswereclassifiedintothreemaingroups:wholesalers/largerretailers;markettraderswithestablishedtradingsitesorstalls;carriedoutinLome
´andmobilehawkers.Interviewswere
inJanuary2008andinBamakoinMarch2008.Some175interviewswereheldintotal,withthenumbersofinterviewsineachlocationdetailedinTable1.Theresearchandinterviewsfocusedontradeinthegarment,householdgoods,andsmallelectronicssectors,whereimportsfrom
Table1.Interviewsummary
Lome
´,TogoBamako,Mali
TotalKey-informant
111021Wholesaler/largerretailer9
11
20
(establishedshopinformalspacesellinginlargequantities)
Markettraders(kioskor523183smallshopinmarketarea)Hawker(tradingillegallyin30
21
51
publicspace,stationaryormobile)Total
10273175
Chinaareincreasinglyreplacinglocalmanufactureorotherimportsources,notablyEuropeandtheMiddleEast.
Thekeyinformantinterviewsexploredissuesoftrademan-agement,thechangingscaleandcharacterofstreettrade,theroleofstreet-tradeinurbanandnationaleconomicpolicy,andtradepolicy.
Forthepurposeofsampling,tradersweregroupedtoreflecttrade-careertrajectoriesoutofpoverty,fromhawkertowholesaler(Lyons&Snoxell,2005b).Interviewswithwhole-salers/largerretailersusedaninterviewscheduletofocusoncurrentbusinessandmarkets,employmenthistory,percep-tionsofmarkettrends,limitsandopportunities,andgenerallylastedforaboutanhour.Interviewswithmarkettradersusedadetailedsemi-structuredquestionnairetopermitin-depthinvestigationofrespondents’socio-economicstatus;businesscharacteristics;incomeandturnover;spatialcharacteristics;registrationandformality;supplyanddistributionnetworks;trading-relevantsocialcapitalsuchassavingsandloansgroups,andvulnerabilities.Theseinterviewsgenerallylastedforaboutoneandahalfhourswithtraderscontinuingtotradeduringtheinterview.Interviewswithhawkerscoveredsimilartopicsbutwerenecessarilybriefer,lastingforabouthalfanhour,andusinganinterviewschedule.
Ineachcity,interviewswerecarriedoutintwomarketareaswherethesaleofChinese-manufacturedconsumergoodswas
mostevident.InLome
´thesurveyareaswereGrandMarche´(themainmarketbuildingat´andthesurroundingdistrict),andHe`dzranawe´Assigame
,andinBamakothecentralbuildingsMe
´andareasurroundingMarche
´market
Roseandtheoutlyingdinemarket.Respondentswereselectedfromtheclothing/textileareas,householdgoodsandconsumerelectronics,includingmobilephones.Traderswererandomlyselectedwithinidentifiedareasinthemarketswithinterviewerscount-ingoffeachfiftheligiblestallintheselectedareasandmovingononeincaseofrefusal.InBamakotheinterviewperiodwithmarkettradersandhawkershadtobecurtailedbecausethemairieannouncedastreetclearanceduringthefieldwork,althoughthisdidnoteventuallytakeplacewhenscheduledfollowingpublicdebate.
6.FINDINGS
(a)UrbanmarkettradingcommunitiesandtrendsinLome
´andBamakoThereiswidespreadconsensusinbothcitiesthattherehasbeenarapidincreaseinthescaleofurbaninformaltradein
thelast5–10yearsbutnoreliabledata(KIinterviewsLome
´andBamako).InLome
´tradeistraditionallyimportant,withwomenformingthelargemajorityofurbanmarkettraders,particularlyinthesaleofcloth,newclothing,food,andhouse-holdgoods,althoughmaletraderspredominateinthesaleofelectricalgoodsandsecond-handclothes.InMali,menformamajorityoftraders,andinformaltradehasincreasedrapidlysince1995,whenthecountryagreedtoabolishfixedpricingandabandonnationalcontroloftradinganddistribution.
Forexample,GrandMarche
´inBamakohoused7,950formaltenantsin2000,butby2008,thenumberhadrisento10,000,anincreaseofover20%(KIinterviewsBamako).Aselse-where,inbothcitieshawkingisoftenthefirstentrypointtocommerceforthepoor.
Inbothcitiesthenatureoftradeisalsochanging,withanincreasedominanceofimportsamongthegoodsforsale.Thedifferentpaceofchangeineachcityreflects––andisre-flectedin––thedifferentcharacterofthetradingcommunities.
HASMERCANTILISMREDUCEDURBANPOVERTYINSSA?775
´,transittradetoinlandTogoandtheregionisimpor-InLome
tant,partlybecauseoftheinfluenceofthefreeport.ChineseimportsarewidelyavailableandthereisanestablishedChi-nesetradingcommunitysomeofwhomhavelivedinTogofor15ormoreyearsalthoughwithmanyrecentarrivals(KI
´).TheonwardtradeandTogo’sreportedlyinterviewsLome
openbordershavedrawnmigrantcommunitiesfromacrosstheregion,includingNigeria,Niger,Mali,BurkinaFaso,Be-nin,andGhana.Overhalfthemarkettradersinterviewedin
´wereinternationalmigrants,sometimeswithahistoryLome
ofmigration,havinglivinginthreeorfourcountriesenroute.
´alsoAlargemajorityofthehawkersinterviewedinLome
camefromabroad(19ofthe30interviewees),andtheothers,fromvariouspartsofTogo.InBamakotheChinesecommu-nityismuchsmaller,andChinesetradershavedifficultyinmanagingtheFrenchlanguage(KIinterviewBamako).Amongstbothmarkettradersandhawkers,themigrantswerefromsmallercitiesorruralareastoBamako.EverymarkettraderinterviewedinBamakowasMalian,andonlyoneofthe21hawkershadcomefromabroad(BurkinaFaso).
Thethreebroadcategoriesoftradersinterviewed––whole-salers,markettraders,andhawkers––representdifferentlevelsofbusinesssizeintermsofcapitalbaseandturnover.Theselevelsarealsoreflected,ingeneralterms,intheextenttowhichsuchbusinessescanbedescribedasinformal(or‘‘extra-le-gal’’).Manyformalbusinesseswerelicensed,andalmostallthoseinterviewedpaidtaxesordailyfees,inBamakotothe
´toEPAM,aprivatecom-mairie(municipality)andinLome
panythatmanagesthecity’smainmarkets.Togoretainsapeddlinglicense,andsomehawkersarelicensedtotrade.Allotherhawkersinterviewedpaiddailyhawkingfees.Incon-trast,inBamakonopeddlinglicenseexistsbuthawkersstillpaydailyfees,toofficials,‘‘gatekeepers’’,orboth.Neitherli-censesnorpaymentoffeesprovideimmunityfromeviction.AsTable2shows,thelargebulkofmarkettradersinter-viewedinbothcitieshadatleastsomeformaleducation(69of83responses),andthepercentagewasverysimilarinthetwocities.However,themarkettradersinterviewedinBama-koweregenerallybettereducated(44%,or11of25respon-dentshadcompletedmorethan10yearsofschoolingcomparedwith12%,or5of52inTogo).Thelowlevelsof
´areparticularlyliteracyamongstmarkettradersinLome
strikinggiventhenationallylowerliteracylevelsinMali(seeabove).Amonghawkers,meaneducationalattainmentswerelowerinBamako(4.9and3.6yearsofschoolcompletedby
´andBamakohawkers,respectively).Lome
Amuchhigherproportionofwomenwereobservedtrading
´inLome´thanininalltheselectedsectorsinGrandMarche
`dzranawe´marketofHe´,orthemarketseithertheouterLome
inBamako,asreflectedintheinterviewsample.Nochildmar-´orBamako.However,kettraderswerefoundineitherLome
´weresignificantlyyoungermarkettradersinterviewedinLome
with64%under35(32of50)comparedwith44%inBamako
´andthreeinBamakowereun-(13of31).OnehawkerinLomeder17.
ThepicturesummarizedinTable2isoftwocontrasting
´,ahighlydynamic,mobile,andtradingcommunities:Lome
opportunisticsociety,andBamako,farmoretraditionalandconservative.Reinforcingthiscontrast,thereisevidenceofamorestableandfamily-basedstructuresurvivinginBamako,withfarhigherratesofmarriageamongmarkettraders;ahigherproportionoftraderswithchildrenoftheirown;andlowerratesofbachelorhood(8of31,or26%,against21of51,or41%).Thereisalsoevidenceofstrongersupporttofam-ilybytradersinBamako,withamuchhigherproportionsup-portingchildreninschool(Table2).Interestingly,tradersinBamakowerealsosupportingtheeducationofchildrenbe-yondtheirimmediatefamily(97%supportingchildreninedu-cation,whileonly77%havechildrenoftheirown),probablyreflectingthestrongextendedfamilytiesstillsurvivinginMali.Inaddition,whiletradersinbothcitiesaremorelikelythannottomakeremittancestofamilymembers,therateamongstintervieweeswashigherinMali(42%against32%).Themeanworkingweekformarkettradersis68hours,comprisingaworkingdayof6–14h,sevendaysaweek,52weeksayear,indicatingthattradingistheirmainoccupation.Physicalworkingconditionsaredifficult,withaninadequatecleaningofmarketsandtradingplaces,poor(orno)sanitaryfacilities,andoftennoregularaccesstowaterorelectricity.Hoursforhawkersaresimilaror,often,longer,asformalmar-ketsaresubjecttoregulatedopeningtimes.However,ingen-´aresomewhatshorterthaneral,workinghoursinLome
workinghoursinBamakoatalltradinglevels.
InallSSAcities,theincomefrommarkettradingisasignif-icantsourceoflocallyraisedrevenues.Mostmarkettradersandallwholesalersinterviewedworkinacceptedtradingareas,whichmaybepublicorprivatefacilities,andalmost
´,28ofthe36mar-allwerepayingatleastsometaxes.InLome
´paidakettradersinterviewedinandaroundGrandMarche
licenseofbetweenCFA12,000–80,000amonth,andonly
`dzranawe´wasnotpayingali-oneofthe16intervieweesinHe
censefee.InBamako13ofthe31intervieweeswerenotpayinglicensefees.AllbutoneoftheunlicensedtraderspaiddailyfeesofCFA100–500aday.
Formarkettraders,negotiatingaccesstolegitimateandse-curespaceisamajorproblem:
Wecanneverforgetallthetroublesinwhichwegetinbeforehavingthe
´areunderlicensetosellhere.Itwasverydifficult....AllmarketsinLome
EPAM.EPAMkeepsorderintheirmarketsandmaintainthem.ThosewhoneedspaceapplytoEPAM,abutmanyindividualspaybribestogettradingspace.EPAMcollectsrentfromeveryonewhosellsinapublicspace,butthecustomersderivelittlebenefitfromthetaxes/ratesthey
´,Lome´).pay.(Markettrader,shoes,Assigame
Table2.Summaryoftradercharacteristics(83respondents)
Percentoftraderswhoare:
n
Internationalmigrants
Withsomeformaleducation
Withmorethan10yearsformaleducationMarriedBachelors
Withdependentchildren
SupportchildrenineducationMakeremittancestorelatives
02611228233010
Bamako
%084445126779732
n294352621302321
´Lome
%5583127141594642
n2969164829535331
All
%3583245635656538
n8183668182818181
Total
%100100100100100100100100
776WORLDDEVELOPMENT
Istartedsellingwithafriendinthemarket,weweresellingsecond-handgoods(jeans,shirts,coats)IlearnthowtotradeandImademanyfriends.AsIraisedsomemoney,Istartedmyownbusinesswith20jeans.ItwasdifficultformeandIhadtostopbecauseIcouldnotpayfeestoEPAM.Istayedathomeforfourmonths.Oneofmycustomerswhowasmyfriend,helpedmeandIstartedagainmybusiness.Dubaiproductsare
affectingsecond-handtrade(Markettrader,secondhandjeans,He
`dzra-nawe
´,Lome´).InBamako,increasedcrowdinginthestreetshasreducedmu-nicipaltoleranceforstreettradeandresultedinrepeatedevic-tions(KIinterviews,localandcentralgovernment).
Municipalityagentsseizedmymerchandiseonthepretextthatitwasspreadoutontheroad,whichwasfalse.Ipaidsothattheyreturnedittome.TheyalsoclosedmystoreunderpretextthatIwassixmonthsinrentarrears,whereasitwasonlyonemonth(Markettrader,radios
andcalculators,Marche
´Rose,Bamako).Themunicipalityserveduswithnoticeofaweektoquitourplaces.WewenttotheChamberofCommercewhoadvisedustoconsultalawyer,whoobtainedadelayofoneyearintheevictionnotice.Nevertheless,threedayslateratnight,municipalityagentsdemolishedourstalls.Westilldon’tknowthereasonfortheevictionsandnootheractivityhasbeen
allowedthere(Markettrader,smallitems,Me
´dine,Bamako).Forhawkers,thesituationismorecomplex.Althoughunli-censedhawkersinbothcitiespaydailytollstooccupytheir
space,inbothcitiestherearefrequentcrack-downsonhawk-ingasaresultofpoliticaldecisions,sometimestopresentabetterimagetovisitingdignitariesorasresponsetopressurefromformaltraders.
Thepoliceharassusateverymoment.Often,theyriflemygoods.Twiceaday.IhavelostgoodstothevalueofperhapsCFA100,000.Also,wepayfines.IsellproductsfromChinaandDubai.Thisiswhatsellsquickly.ForChinait’stheprice;ForDubai,thequality.Therearemoreproductsforthecheapgoods(andthereforetheChinese)(Hawker,trou-sersandT-shirts,GrandMarche
´,Bamako).WhenIwasahawker,municipalityagentsconfiscatedmygoods
althoughIhadnotinfringedthemarketrulesofMe
´dine.Ihadtopaymoneytogetthegoodsback(Markettrader,telephoneaccessories,Me
´dine,Bamako).Theywantustostop.Theydon’twantustocirculateinthemarkets,butwecan’tstopinafixedposition,becausetheychaseusawaywhenwe
stop(Hawker,ladies’shoes,Lome
´).Manybusinesseswererelativelynew.Some62%ofmarket
traders(50of81)hadtradedforlessthansixyears,and55%(28of51)ofthehawkersinterviewedhadtradedforlessthanfouryears.Incontrasthowever,tradersinandaroundAssigame
´severaloftheTogolese
wereworkinginbusinessessetupbytheirmothersorgrandmothers,illustratingthelongtradinghistoryintheregion.
Mygrandmotherstartedsellingpills,initially,butwasarrested,sochan-gedtotextiles.Lateronshedecidedtogointohouseholdgoods.Mymotherhasbeentradingforaround30yearsnow,mysisterisalsowork-ing.Theyhavealsosoldriceandbabyclothesinthepast(Markettrader,
cookeryitems,Assigame
´,Lome´).Commerceinbothcitiesisarelativelymobilesector,withpeo-plemovinginandoutofstreettrade.Ofthefortyonemarket
tradersinthisstudywhoreportedtheirjobhistory,48%(19)hadenteredcommerceafterworkinginservices(restaurateur,teacher,secretary,anddriver),manufacturing,orconstruc-tioninthe1990s.Ofthehawkerswhorespondedwelloverhalf(68%)hadworkedinothersectors,generally,agriculture.ParticularlyinBamako,manyreturntoaruralhomeeachyearfortheharvestseason,thuscombiningurbanandrurallivelihoods.
Onceincommerce,tradersprovideacruciallinkinthelive-lihoodschain.AsTable2shows,mostmarkettradersinbothcitiesmakeremittancestorelatives.Thepercentageofhawkers
whoreportedsendingremittanceswasalsoveryhigh(57%,or
17of30interviewsinLome
´,and71%,or151of21interviewsinBamako––notshown).AlthoughtherateofsupporttotendedfamiliesismuchhigherinBamakothaninLome
´ex-,itisinterestingthateveninthedynamicenvironmentofLome
´,thepracticeissocommon.Indeed,therateinMalimaybeunusu-allyhighforsub-SaharanAfrica––forexamplerecentfindingsinlarge-scalestudyinTanzania,foundthat55%ofrural-ur-banmigrantscontinuingtomakeremittancesafter5yearsinthecity(Lyons&Msoka,2008).Farfewerofthehawkers
interviewedinbothLome
´andBamakoarealsoreceivingoccasionalremittancesorhelpwithstartingabusinessfromfamilyoverseas(30%and27%,respectively).
(b)PerceptionsofimportanceoftheChineseimporttradeVariousauthorshaveexploredtheprofoundimpactsofChi-nese-manufacturedimportsonmanufacturinginofSSA(Kaplinsky,Morris,&Readman,2002;Goldsteinetal.,2006;Kaplinskyetal.,2006),butimpactsoncommercehavebeenmuchlessfullyaddressed.
WhilethegrowthinimportsfromChinaoverthelastfewyearshasbeenverysignificant,acrossallsectorsofmanufac-turedgoods,theresearchindicatesthatChinese-manufacturedgoodsaresubstitutingothersourcesofequivalentgoods,undercuttingbothlocalmanufactureandotherimports.Themajorityofwholesalersandmarkettradersinterviewedinbothcitiesreportedthattheirmainproductwasimported(95%and93%inTogoandMali,respectively).Amongthosesellingclothes,textiles,shoes,andaccessoriestheprevalenceofimportswasevenhigher(100%and95%).
SometradersconsideredthattheimportofChinesegoodsismakingnewmarketsaccessibletoAfricanconsumers.
IappreciatetheChinesetradingpolicies.First,theChinesetakeintoac-countthelivingconditionsofAfricanswhenmanufacturinggoodsforAfrica.ChinesegoodsarecheaperthanEuropeangoods.Second,theysettledtheirbusinessinAfrica,especiallyinTogotobeclosetocustom-ers.theyarewholesalers,importersatthesametime(Markettrader,
electricalgoods,Assivito-GrandMarche
´,Lome´).OthersareconcernedthatChinesetradeisundermining
establishedlocalmanufactureandcommerce––thelasttextilefactoryinTogoclosedsomeyearsago(KIinterview).Therehasbeenconsiderableimpactonthecloth,akeyproduceinGrandMarche
´saleofDutch´waxed
inLome,developedinthe19thcenturyasatradingcommodity,andlatterlyim-ported,andalsoonthesaleofimportedatHe
`second-handclothes
dzranawe´,TheChinesearecopyingthedesignsofthecloth,producingmorecheaply,andsellingcheaper.Theyareundercuttingthemarket.Alawwaspassedlastyeartorestrictpeoplewhoarewholesalersinwaxedclothfromalsoretailing;aDecreehasbeenissuedbutithasnotyetbeen
implemented(Wholesaler,waxedcloth,Lome
´).Themajorproblemforusedclothessellersisthatthereisnomoneyinthecountryandpeoplecannotaffordqualitygoods.Africansarepoor,sothe
Chinesegoodssuitthem(Markettrader,secondhandbags,He
`dzra-nawe
´,Lome´).However,competitionisrapidlyerodingpricesandprofits.Pricesvarywiththeprecisetechnologyandqualityusedbut,inthegarmentsectorlow-gradeChinese-madeclothesaresoldforaslittleas10–15%ofwesternsecond-handgoods;simi-larly,imitationwaxprintssellforabout20%ofthecostofthetraditionalDutchimportsandlocalmanufacture;andplasticutensilsundercutlocalmetal,pottery,andotherhouse-hold-goodscrafts.Wholesalersandimportersofsecond-handclothes,African-madetextiles,andwestern-madeelectronicshaveseenstocksstagnateandprices––andincomes––fall.
HASMERCANTILISMREDUCEDURBANPOVERTYINSSA?777
ManyhavenowexpandedtoincludeChineseimportsInter-viewswithwholesalersofconsumerelectronicsconfirmedthatthecostofastandardTVhashalvedinfiveyears.
Businessisfallingbecausecheapimportsareundercuttingthetraditionalmarket.CostdifferencebetweenDutchgoods(55,000Fforafullpiece––12yards)andChinese(11,000F)isenormous(Wholesaler,highquality
waxcloth,Lome
´).Furtheralongthedistributionchain,thesamepatternisre-flected.Somehawkersarenotawareofthemanufacturingori-ginoftheirgoods––theybuywhateverthewholesalersupplies.
However,anexaminationoftheproductssuggestedthatover70%,or36ofthe51hawkersinterviewedsoldChinesegoodsastheirprimaryproduct.Ofthese,theoverwhelmingmajorityexplainedthattheirchoiceresultedfromeitherimprovedeaseofentryintotrade,orhigherprofitability.
(c)Opportunitiesandconstraintsofthetrade
Thequalitativedatainresponsetotheopenquestion‘‘HowhaveChineseimportsaffectedthemarket-place?’’pro-viderichinsightsintotheopportunitiesandchallengesinthetrade.Interestingly,althoughpricecompetitionistheprimaryfactor,botheconomicandpolitical/culturalthemesemerge.
(i)Economicthemes
Thefirstandmostimportantdriverofchangeissimplyprice.Mosttradersseeaningpower(pouvoird’acha
ˆ‘‘economiccrisis’’orfallinpurchas-t)asthemaindriverofdemandforChinesegoods.Amarkettraderinsecond-handclothes(fripp-erie)representsawidespreadviewamongtradersinboth
Lome
´andBamakothemassoftheircustomersarepoor––toopoortodrivegrowthinthemarketplacethroughthecon-sumptionofrelativelyexpensivegoods.Thestagnationofreg-ularemploymentforexampleingovernmentserviceshasleftavacuumindemandforhigh-endgoods,suchasimportedsec-ond-handjeansfromtheUSA,Europe,orAustralia,obligingsellerstobroadentheirrangetoincludethelower-quality,butcheaperChinesegoods(Dubaiproduct––socalledbecausetheyareboughtnotdirectlyfromChinabutfromintermediarywholesalersinDubai).
Secondistheconsequentwidespreadavailabilityofnewconsumergoods,importantforstyle.Onesecond-handclothesseller,echoinganumberofsimilarcomments,wasoftheviewthat:
CustomersliketheChinesegoodsbecauseoftheircleannessandsharp-ness,buttheproblemisthatChinesegoods,especiallyclothes,don’tlast.Sopeoplewholikewearingqualitythingsprefersecondhandclothes
(Markettrader,second-handclothes,He
`dzranawe´,Lome´).Otherscitedtheimportanceofkeepingupwitheconomicpro-gress––accordingtoatraderinBamako,
Withthedevelopmentoftelecomsandglobalisationithasbecomecom-pulsoryforalltousetelephones,sothereisabigneedandwearethesup-pliers.IsellChineseproductslikeSiemens,Novo”(Markettrader,
mobilephones,Me
´dine,Bamako).(ii)Politicalthemes
ThethirdargumentputforwardforswitchingtoChinesegoodsexpressesabroaderreadinesstoengagewithChinainpreferencetoEurope.Asmallnumberofmarkettradersmen-tionculturalandpoliticalargumentsintheirexplanation,includingliberationfromex-colonialEuropeandasensethatthenew,Chinesetradingpartnershipisthefuture,andbetter
attunedtoAfrica.Severalmarkettradersexpressedadmira-tionforChina’sAfrica-tailoredexportpolicy:
“Forme,ChinahascometotherescueofAfrica.Threequartersofour
populationispoorandtheycannotbuyprimarynecessitieslikesoap,milk,sugar,coffeebecauseitisproducedinEuropeanditisexpensive.Ifwewerein1990,IcouldnothavesoldglassesbecauseIamnotrichenough.ThisisnowtheopportunityformetotradewithChina.Whole-salersarecomplainingbecausewethepoorcanalsobuythesameprod-uctandatthesametimepriceintheChineseshops–-thisisjustcompetitionanditwillboosttradeinTogo(Hakwer,wineglasses,Assi-game
´,Lome´).”AnumberofrespondentsstatedinformallythattheChinese
respectAfricansmorethantheirEuropeancounterparts,andthispredisposedtheAfricantraderstodealwiththem.ThissupportsfindingsfrominterviewswithAfricantradersfromacrossEastandWestAfricainGuangzhou(Lyonsetal.,2008).
(d)Cumulativeandunintendedconsequences
Initially,theintroductionofnewconsumergoodsintoamarketleadstradersatalllevelstoreporthighlevelsofprof-itability.Therelativelyrecentexpansionoftelecommunica-tionsintheregionprovidessuchanicheatthemomentforsometradersatalllevels.
Mobilephones’tradeisanewbusinessthatmakesyourichifyouareanimporter.Withthedevelopmentoftelecomsandglobalisationithasbe-comecompulsoryforalltousetelephones,sothereisabigneedandwe
arethesupplier”(Markettrader,Assigame
´––GrandMarche´,Lome´).Manytradershavemadegoodprofitsfromthetrade.Forexample,a29-yearoldtraderfromLome
´,sellingChinesejew-elrybypostacrosstheCFA-regionhadbuiltthreehousesasadirectresultofbusinesssuccess:
Ilikethis[Chinese]trade...wearemakingprofitswiththem.Chineseproductsarenotexpensive,andwedon’tneedtotraveltoChina.Iknowthatpeoplearecomplaining,butIcan’tcomplain(Markettrader,jew-elry,GrandMarche
´,Lome´).AnothertraderinAssigame
´sellingsyntheticleatherhandbags,said
WhenIstartedsellingwithmyauntIwassurprisedbythehighprofitlev-els.SoIdecidedtosavemoneytogointotrade.WhenItoldmymotherthatIhadearnedenoughtostartmyownbusiness(CFA700,000in5years)shecouldn’tbelieveit,andgavemeCFA300,000soIstartedwith
CFA100,0000!(Markettrader,bags,Assigame
´––GrandMarche´,Lome
´).However,themarketforconsumergoodsineverysectorhasattractedincreasingnumbersoftradersateverylevel.Asami-granttradefromNigerinLome
´’sGrandMarche´said:‘‘Chi-nesegoodsareaboontoallwhohopetoentertradebutdon’thavemuchcapital’’.Thus,longerterm,thecompetitionforsaleofChinese-manufacturedgoodsisintense,withrespondentsatalllevelsreportingcontinuingpressureonprices,fallingprofitmargins,andfallingprofits(althoughsomehawkersstillamasssufficientcapitalforupwardmobility).Informingthecommentsofallbuttwoofthe52markettradersinterviewed
inLome
´,forexample,isastrongperceptionthatthecon-sumer-goodsmarketasawhole,haspeaked.Twomainstagesareidentifiableinthisdecline.
First,thereisthepressureonthepriceoflocalproducts,orofproductsfrompreviouslyestablishedimportsources,fromthelowpricesofnewlyimportedChinesegoods.Thismeansthattradersinsuchgoodsmustselltheirstocksatwellbelowtheirexpectedsalepriceandoftenatwellbelowthe
778WORLDDEVELOPMENT
purchasingprice,orwatchtheircustomersdriftaway,whilecompetitorsflourish.
In1995ImadeaprofitofCFA180,000,butChineseimportsarenothelpingus.WhatwesellbeforeatCFA1,200nowtheChinesesellatCFA300...PriortoarrivalofChineseIhadimportedalotofgoodsfromChina.However...theChinese...havebroughtinthesamegoodsmorecheaply,andIhavenotbeenabletosellmygoods.Thisisabiglossofcapital.ConsequentlyIhavedevelopedahealthproblemofnotbeingabletosleepatnightuntilItakedrugs(Wholesaler/largeretailer,new
clothes,Lome
´).Tradewasflourishinghereinthe1990swhenIcame,butnowithasbe-comeverydifficult(Markettrader,clothes,Koke
´time´-GrandMarche´,Lome
´).WhenIstartedthebusinessin2003,itwasmoreprofitable,butnow[it]
ispoor(Markettrader,smallelectricalitems,Lome
´).Iwouldliketoremindyouthatsalesweregoodherein2000whenIstartedhere,butnowitisverydifficultandweareverysorryforthat.Chineseimportsareaffectingus(Markettrader,second-handshirts,He
`dzranawe´,Lome´).Wearenotselling.Ourexpensesarehigherthanthedailyincome.Peo-pleprefernowbrandnewTVandradio.TheypreferChineseproductsbecauseitischeaperandnew.(Markettrader,second-handelectricalgoods,MarcheRose,Bamako).
Second,competitionamongtraderssellingChinese-manufac-turedgoodsdeveloped,andChineseandlocaltraderscompeteforlocalcustom.Chinesetradersinterviewedwerereticentandsomeemphasizedtheirgoodrelationswithlocaltraders.How-everlocaltradersseethemselvesasdisadvantagedbecauseoftheirdependenceonChinesetradersforaccesstoimportedgoods,becausetheChinesetraderscanimportdirectlyfromfactoriesandsuppliers––manyareprovidingsalesforfamily-runfirms,whereasAfricantradershavetobuyfromwholesal-ersortraveltoChinatoimport.
IntheolddayswesoldDutchWax,butnowourproductsaremadeinChina(orVietnamorHK).OncetheChinesehadbegunimitatingtheDutchWax,wecouldnotselltheoriginal,sotheDutchWaxlostitsva-lue.(Wholesaler,Dutchwaxcloth,GrandMarche
´,Lome´).IhavebeensellingChinesegoodslongtermbeforethenewwaveofChi-nesegoodsinAfricanmarkets.MyAlbumsareChinesemadeproduct.Before2000therewerefewalbumsellersandthoughChineseproductsarelessdesiredbecauseoftheirlowerquality,Imadeaprofit.Todayitisnolongerpossiblebecausetheproductsareavailableineverycornerofthestreetsandthepriceisreduced(Haker,photoalbums,Sakomi,
GrandMarche
´,Lome´).ItisnoteworthythatinthefaceofcompetitionfromChinese
traders,competitorsfromallovertheCFAregionandbe-yond,inNigeriaandGhana,areacceptedas‘‘local’’.MaliansareviewedaspreferringtodobusinesswithotherMaliansyet,
eveninLome
´,theChineseminorityisoftenidentifiedand‘‘othered’’:
TheChinesegoodsarecheapandtheChinesearealsosellingthesameproducts,thustakingawayourcustomersandreducingourprofits––wecannotpriceourgoodslowerthanthem.TheChinesesettledtheirshopsinthemarketandcompetewiththelocaltraders.Theirpricesarevery
goodsocustomerspreferthem(Markettrader,householdgoods,Marche
´Rose,Bamako)
ToobtainaccurateinformationaboutChinainAfricaishard.WehavetotalktotheChinesewholesalers,whohavetheirshopsinthemarket
(Markettrader,schoolbooksandstationery,Assigame
´,Lome´)ThestudyinLome
´andBamakoconfirmedthecomplexandconflictingrelationshipsamongChinesetraders,reportedelsewhere.Forexample,mutualmistrustintheChinesetrad-ingcommunityhasbeenwelldescribedinNamibiabyDobler(2005),whileinCapeVerdeHaugenandCarling(2005)de-scribedagradualdeclineoftheChinesetradingcommunity,asaprogressivepricecompetitionamongitsmembers,vyingwitheachothertosellhouseholdgoodsforlocalconsump-
tion,drovedownprofitmarginsanderodedtraders’capitalbase.
TheChinesewholesalersinterviewedinthisstudy,inLome
´bothandBamako,reporteddownwardpressureonpricesandprofitmarginfromcompetitionwithotherChineseimporters.TheintensecompetitionamongChinesetradersisassociatedwithmutualdistrust,andthereisverylittlesocial-izingwithintheChinese‘‘community’’(KIinterviewwiththepresidentofBamako’snewlyformedChineseChamberofCommerce).
TherearetrustrelationsbetweenChineseimportersandlocalwholesal-ers.AllwholesalersweregivenXmaspresents(Markettrader,clothfor
muslimprayerrobes,Assivito-GrandMarche
´,Lome´).TheChinesebusinessmenallliveinChinatown,buttheydonotsocialise[witheachother].ManyChinesebusinessmenheredonotjointhenewChamberofCommerce.Somearetoopoor.Somewanttoremainprivate(KIinterview,Chinesecommunityleader,Bamako).
(e)Emergentstrategies
TheopeningupoftheChina–Africatradehasoccurredinparallelwithotherstructuralchanges,whichhavedrivengrowthintheinformaleconomy.Theincreasedstreet-tradingandcompetitionbetweeninformalandformaltradershavecreatedpoliticalpressurestoreducemunicipaltoleranceforstreettradeandresultedinawaveofenforcementmeasuresacrossSSA(Lyons&Msoka,2008).Withtheexceptionofthemobilephonesector,tradersinconsumergoodsarefacedwithfallingprofitabilityandincreasedcompetition.Opportu-nitiesinhomecountriesanddistrictsandinotheremploymentsectorsareseenasextremelylimited,buttherewasalsothehopementionedbymanyhawkersthattheywouldbeamongthesmallnumberstoachievesuccess.Facedwithsuchdown-wardpressuresonprofitability,howdotradersacttobettertheirpositioninthemarket-place?
Figure3presentsinadiagrammaticformthevaluechainsforthelargebulkofChinese-manufacturedgoodsreaching
consumersinLome
´andBamako.ThispicturehasbeenbuiltupfromresearchbytheauthorsinbothChina(Lyonsetal.,2008),andEastandWestAfrica(Brown,2006;Lyons&Mso-ka,2008;Lyons&Snoxell,2005a,2005b).Acrossthetopofthediagram,boxesidentifythemainbodiesofregulationwhichgovernactivitiesateachstage,whileacrossthebottom;themainspatialnodesonthejourneyfromfactorytocon-sumerareidentified.
Theactorsnumbered30–50inthediagramarethesubjectof
thispaperanddescribethetradingsituationinLome
´.ThemarketsofbothcitiesincludeChinesewholesalers(31)and
indigenouswholesalers(33).Lome
´alsohasasignificantpop-ulationofregionalmigrants(32).Thearrowsidentifytypical
pathsfortheflow´itals,fromLome
´ofgoodsfromLome
tootherregionalcap-toTogoleseprovinces,andwithinLome´it-self(NGnotallpathsidentifiedinthetextbelowareexplicitlyshowninthediagram).
Sinceeverytransaction(ellipse)representsapointatwhichvalueisaddedtoaproduct,eachtradermustaimtominimizethenumberoftransactionsbetweenhim/herandthefactory,ontheonehand;andbetweenhim/herandtheconsumer,ontheotherhand.Atthesametime,theinternationalnatureofthetrade,thedifferentlegal,cultural,andlinguisticbarrierstomovingpeople,money,andgoodsbetweennodes,createawiderangeoftransactioncosts,andthereisanincentivetominimizethese.Beingabletoparticipateinthecompetitiononpriceinsellingtotheconsumer,requirestraderstooperateinawaywhichreducesthesecosts,inotherwords,toreducethenumberofnodesonthechaininwhichtheyareoperating.
HASMERCANTILISMREDUCEDURBANPOVERTYINSSA?779
Figure3.MultiplevaluechainsforChinese-manufacturedgoods.
´andBamakohaveseveralTheChinesetradersinLome
advantagesintrade.TheyareabletoexportdirectlyfromthewholesalerorthefactoryinChina,reducingtheintermedi-atetransactions,andtheyareabletocommunicateeffectivelywithChinesesuppliersandregulatorsatthatend,reducingtheirtransactioncosts(although,particularlyinBamako,theyfacetransactioncostsinSSA).Theyarealsoabletoundercutlocalwholesalersandcreatedirectlinkstomarkettradersandhawkers(31–42–52;butalso,31–52(notshown)).Whethertrueornot,theperceptionofsomeintervieweeswasthatChi-nesetradersreceivedfavorabletreatmentinrelationtoimportregulationsandcustoms,aswellassecuringmorefavorabletermswhendealingwithChinesemanufacturers.
Figure3showsthat‘‘traditional’’distributionsnetworks,drawingonethnicity-basedsocialcapital,stillfunctioninthismarket.LinkscanbedrawnbackwardsfromChinesewhole-´tomanufacturersanddistributorsinGuang-salersinLome
dong;andfromAfricanwholesalerstocompatriotexporters,oftenfamilymembers,inGuangzhou.Equally,linkscanbe
´toco-ethnicretailersdrawnforwardfromwholesalersinLome
andhawkersinthecity(e.g.,33–42–52or32–42–53),intheprovinces(33–42–41),andinabroad(32–44–54).Thus,many
´,havingmigratedfromNigeria(orNigerianstradinginLome
Niger,Coted’Ivoire,Benin,Cameroon,andotherwestAfri-cancountries),oftensource(thoughnotexclusively)from
´.AncountrymeninChinaandsellontocountrymenLome
importantelementofsuchstrategiesistrust(Brown,Lyons,&Dankoco,inpress).TheflowofarrowsinFigure3clearlyshowsthatgoodsflowalongnational(andethnic)links,andthatthisisrepresentedinthedistributionnetworksestab-lished.
However,thepressureontraderstoreducethenumberofnodesthroughwhichtheirsupplychainspasshascreatedstrongincentivestoby-passthesetraditionalroutes.Hawkers,traditionallyreliantongoodsoncreditfromtrusted(andtrusting)wholesalersfromtheirbrotherhoodandethnicnetworks(Lyons&Snoxell,2005b,Porter,Lyons,&Potts,2007)havebeenenabledbythelowcapitalrequirementsofChinese-manufacturedgoodstobuymorecheaplydirectlyfromChinesewholesalers(31–52).Similarly,retailersregularlybypassco-ethnicwholesalers(31–42),althoughalltradersinterviewed,bothChineseandAfrican,insistedthatChinesewholesalersneverextendcredit.Someretailersandhawkerssucceedinshorteningsupplychainsstillfurther,bymakingmoredirectlinkswithChina(0–(11)–22–42).Atthesametime,tradersstrivetoreducetheirdependenceonintermediariesfordistribution,withwholesalerssellingtohawkersandindividu-als,aswellasretailers;Retailerssellingtohawkers(andthroughhawkers)aswellasdirecttocustomers.
Asecondstrategyadoptedbytradersisthedevelopmentofmultipledistributionchainsalthoughopportunitytodosovariesconsiderablywithtraders’positioninthevaluechain.Hawkershavelittlefreedomtomaneuver,exceptinchangingtherangeofgoodsinwhichtheytrade.Retailers,wholesalers,andimportersusevariousstrategiestobuildsupplychainstomorethanonemarket(forexample33or23mightlinkdi-rectlyto41,42,43,44––aswellasby-passingsomeofthesetodealdirectlywithtradersfurtherdownthechain.
780WORLDDEVELOPMENT
However,opportunityisalsoconstrainedbytheconditionsofparticularbusinesses.Itmighthavebeenexpectedthat,con-strainedastheyare,hawkerswouldbelessoptimisticabout
theirprospectsthanothers.Nevertheless,inbothLome
´andBamakohawkersremainedmostoptimistic,andalargemajority(70%,or36ofthe51hawkersinterviewed)reportedthattheirbusinesswasgrowing.Theoptimismamongsthawk-ersinbothcountriesmaybebecausehawkingisusedasashort-termsteppingstonetoamoreestablishedtradingposi-tion,althoughveryfewreportedbeingabletosave.
Incontrast,manymarkettradersseethemselvesastrappedbylowprofitsandwithlittleroomformaneuver.Someareex-tremelyreluctanttoventureintonewareasorchangethebal-anceoftheirgoods.
Thisiswhatwedoandwhatweknowhowtodo.IfGodwantsustosuc-ceed,wewill(Markettrader,mobilephones,GrandMarche
´,Bamako).Wholesalersfallintotwogroups.Thefirstarewellestablished
intheChinesetrade,andmaybeabletoimprovetheirprofitmarginsrelativetoothers,particularlyiftheyhavedirectlinkswithChina.Forexample,aNigerianshopowneroutside
Lome
´cathedralsaidthathismainconcernnowistofindstrat-egieswhichcanconvincehiscustomerstobuyhisgoods,‘‘whilesearchingforotheropportunities’’.Heissavingtotraveloverseastotrade.Another,atextilewholesalerinBamakohassenthisyoungerbrothertoChinaseveraltimesayeartobuyfabricssince2000.Othersareestablishingadditionaloutletsincountriesthroughouttheregion,sometimesinvolatileareas
seenaspotentialgrowthareas,suchasCo
ˆted’IvoireandDRCongo,andseeingrapidgrowth.However,theseoptimis-tictraderswereaminority.
Incontrast,manyrespondents’commentswerepervadedbyresignation:
Chinesegoodsbusinessisprofitable,butifyouaresellerandyouareknownasclothesseller,youcannotconvertyourselfintoChinesegoodsseller,becauseyouwillloseyourcustomers.SothosewhowereusedclothessellershavesomeChinesegoodsintheirstocksmusttellthetruthtotheirregularcustomers!(Markettrader,second-handclothes,He
`dzranawe´,Lome´).Chinesebecomeourmajorcompetitors.Theychallengeus,butwedon’thaveenoughmoneytostand.So,mostofourbrothertradersareleaving
TogoforCdI.(Markettrader,shoes,Hollando-GrandMarche
´,Lome´).Thus,theadoptionofthesestrategiesisunevenandtraders’
attitudesrangefrombuoyantoptimismtoprofounddespair.
7.DISCUSSION
Thisresearchexaminedthehypothesisthat,fromthetrad-ers’perspectives,therapidinfluxoftraderstothemarketforChinese-manufacturedconsumergoodswasundermin-ingmarketopportunities.Findingsarethat,whiletradersexperiencedinitialgrowthfollowingfromtheincreaseineffec-tivedemandforrelativelylow-pricesChinese-manufacturedconsumergoods,subsequentgrowthinsupplyhasnotbeenmatchedbygrowthindemand.
Withindifferentstrandsofthevaluechain,certaintypesoftraderbenefitattheexpenseofothers,yetinnogroupisthegrowthsufficienttoaccommodatethemassiveinfluxofen-trants.Moreover,traders’analysisoftheexistingeconomictrendsdoesnotsuggestthatdemandwillsignificantlygrowinthefuture,astheyseenoprospectofgrowingpurchasingpowerinthewiderpopulationstheyserve.
Thus,despitethedifferentpositionsofLome
´andBamakointhedistributionchainanddifferencesinthetwotradingsoci-eties,describedabove,thefindingssuggestthatmostactors
inthemarket––wholesalers,markettraders,orhawkers,Afri-cansorChinese––sharetheviewthattheprospectsforlong-termgrowtharelimited.Theinferencefromtraderstoriesisthatthemarketaffordedshort-termopportunitiesforrealpov-ertyreduction,butthatthishasbecomealargelysurvivalistsector,withlowprofitmarginsdependentoncostcuttingratherthangrowth.
Givenfallingprofitmargins,growingcompetition,andre-peatedstreetclearancesofhawkers,whyisthenumberoftrad-ersincreasing;andtowhatextentaretradersawareoftheunintended,cumulativeconsequencesoftheiractions?
Thestoriestoldbyhawkersclearlypointtoalackofviablelivelihoodalternativesineitheragricultureorformalwork.Theircapitalinvestmentisminimalandoverheadsarekeptlow,oftenbybuyingtinyamountsofstockperday,ortakinggoodsoncredit.Theyaregenerallyabletosubsistandsome-timestoincreasetheircapital.Forexample,oneyoungNige-rianstartedhawking,andoveraperiodof18yearsmovedintothewholesaletradeinsecond-handclothes.WhenviewedhehadjustopenedonestallinGrandMarche
´inter-sellingnewChineseclothing,andwashopingtoopenasecondstall.Markettradersarecontinuingalong-standingtraditionof
tradeinWestAfrica.Togohasbeenanentrepo
ˆtformanyyears,andoldermarkettradingbusinesses,particularlythosetradinginwaxedcloth,areofteninheritedbysecondorthirdgenerationentrepreneurs––theemergingChina–Africatradethuscontinuesalong-standingtradition.InMalitradingisof-tenpartofacomplexlivelihoodstrategycombiningseasonalagriculturalworkwithoff-seasonurbantrade.Thestrategiesforgrowthrelyonethnicsocialcapitalforobtaininggoodsoncredit,butalsoonthesubsequentshoppingaroundforgoodsfromanincreasinglyopengroupofsuppliers––retailersandwholesalers,Chineseandlocal.However,strategiesopentothemarelimitedbythefallingvalueoftheirstock,fixedas-sets,andsocialcapital.
Wholesalersandlargeretailerscanemployabroadrangeofstrategieswhichincludewideningtheirclientelelocallybysell-ingdirectlytohawkersaswellastomarkettraders,andattemptingtofindclientsinmoredifficult,oremergingecon-omies.Crucialinthisarecross-borderethnicnetworksevi-dencedinboththeoriginsoftradersandtheircomplexpatternsofremittancesand,particularlyinBamako,collectivefamilystrategies.Nevertheless,manywholesalersdonotseeopportunitiesforgrowthandareresignedtoaperiodofde-cline.
Inessence,theseeminglyinexorablefloodofnewentrantstothesemarkets,andtheresistanceofestablishedtraderstoleave,reflectaperceptionthatthealternativesarelimitedand,generally,worse.
Whileovercrowdingofmarketsisnotunusualineconomicterms,thecriticalfactorhereisthatthelocalurbaneconomiesarerelativelysmall,andthetradehasbecomesowidespreadthatitissqueezingoutestablishedmanufactureandcom-merce,potentiallyleavingthewholeurbaneconomyvulnera-bletochange.Forthesectorasawhole,theoutcomescanbeconsideredperverse,underminingthemarketforlocalman-ufacturedproducts,andfurtherrestrictingalternativeinvest-mentandlivelihoodpossibilities.
FollowingtherecentreviewofurbaninformaleconomiesinSSA(Skinner,2008),itisusefultoreflectonhowthefindingspresentedaboveareabletoenrichthatdebate.First,assum-marizedinFigure3,findingsindicatethatthecomplexweboflinksbetweenformalandinformalactorsintheSSAurbaneconomyidentifiedbyMoser(1978)andCarrandChen(2002)havesurvivedthedeclineofthemanufacturingsector,thetransferoffocusofAfricaneconomiestocommerce,and
HASMERCANTILISMREDUCEDURBANPOVERTYINSSA?781
thedevelopmentbyamultitudeofactorsofcomplextrans-borderlinks––andcontinuestobereinvented,changeandadapt.
Second,despitethesechanges,thediscussionoftradeprac-ticesandtrader–supplierlinksmentionedabovealsosuggeststhecontinuumofformalityidentifiedbyanumberofauthors(Potts,2007).Mosttraders––wholesalers,markettradersorhawkerspayfortheirtradingspace,evenifnotlicensedandthushavesomedegreeoflegitimacy,butstreettraderslacksecurityfromharassmentandevictions.Evictionswerecom-monplaceinMali,whereasinTogotheprivatizationofmar-ketmanagementledtomorestability,butgettingspacewasdifficult.However,thefindingsfromthisresearchsuggestthatforthelargemajorityofactorstheimportsectorisunlikelytobemorethanasurvivalstrategy.
Finally,returningtostructurationtheory,thetheoreticalframeworkofthispaper,twotypesofcauseareposedinthatdebateforthedevelopmentofperverseaggregateoutcomes:actorignoranceandactorselfishness.
First,perverseaggregateoutcomescanresultfromindivid-uallybeneficialdecisions.Thus,hawkersaremakinganopti-malmoveasindividuals,butbecauseoflimitedeffectivedemand,theycontributetothedeclineofthemarket.Asshownabove,marketentryissometimesundertakeninhope-fulignorance.However,underlyingthedeterminationofindi-vidualsinarangeofmarketpositionstoremainincommerceisnotignoranceaboutcumulativeoutcomesandmarkettrends,assuggestedbyGiddens,butacombinationofhopeagainsthopeandknowledgeofhowlimitedopportunityisinothereconomicspheres.
Second,someaspectsofperverseaggregateoutcomescanarisefromfailuretoactcollectively,ortorespectthecollectivewill.Theresearchwasdesignedtoevaluatetheactionsoftrad-ersasindividualsinalargemarket-place.Yetthefindingsshowmanytobeactingcollectively,aspartofafamily,ortobedrawingonethnicandcommunityties.Thisinfluencessupplychains,accesstocreditanddistributionnetwork.Un-
likecartels,identifiedasaclassicstrategybyGiddens,inthiscompetitiveenvironmentcollectivismcanhaveanimpactontraders’costs.Thustheentrytothemarketofmoretradersisfacilitatedinaggregate,anddownwardpressureonthemar-ketismaintained.
Itismoredifficulttofindinstructurationtheoryanexplana-tionfortheinitiativeswhichtradersdonottake.Whiletraderscompeteonpriceandinitiatechangestotheirsupplychain,theydonotcompeteoninnovationintheirgoods.Furtherre-searchisneededtoinvestigatethelinksbetweenindividualstrategyandconformity.
Thefindingspresentedheresuggestdynamicbutverydiffer-´andentmarketsintheurbantradingcommunitiesofLome
Bamako,withdifferentrolesinthecomplexvaluechainsintheimportofChinese-manufacturedconsumergoods.Indica-tionsarethatalthoughforsomethetradeismakingcheapconsumergoodsaccessible,withhighpovertylevelsintheur-baneconomiesstudied,themainimpactofcheapimportsissubstitution(ratherthananoverallincreaseindemand)whichthusundermineslocalmanufactureandestablishedtrade.Thetradersinvolvedinthisprocessarefarfromsecure,notfullyrecognizedbygovernmentsaslegitimateeconomicactors,althoughalmostallpayalicensefeeordailytollindicatingsomedegreeofformalitywithrespecttotradingspaceandreg-istration.Theresearchwasundertaken,butperhapspresaged,therecentglobaldeclineintrade;itcanbeanticipatedvulner-abilityhasincreasedsignificantlysinceourfieldworkwascom-pleted.
Thetradeisephemeral,andunlikelytoleadtolong-termpovertyreductionwithoutnationalstrategiestoprotectindig-enousproductsandmarkets.ThefindingssuggestthatitisimportantforAfricanurbaneconomiesthattheearlyprofitsfromthegrowthintradeareinvestedinother,labor-intensiveandhighvalue-addedsectors.Withoutsuchgrowth,effectivedemandcannotrise,andnewentrantstothelabormarketwillcontinuetobeforcedintotrading.
REFERENCES
Alexander,N.(1997).Internationalretailing.Chichester:Blackwell.
Brown,A.(Ed.)(2006).Contestedspace:Streettrading,publicspaceandlivelihoodsindevelopingcities.Rugby:ITDGPublishing.
Bhowmick,S.(2007).Opportunitycreationasstructuration:Illustrationsfromthreetechnologyentrepreneurialinitiatives.InternationalJournalofTechnoentrepreneurship,1(2),129–145.
BNETD(2001).Bamako,Mali,Citydevelopmentstrategyreport,Bureau
ˆteNationald’EtudesTechniquesetdeDeveloppement,(BNETD)Co
d’Ivoire. Brown,A.,Lyons,M.,&Dankoco,I.S.(inpress).StreettradersandtheemergingspacesforcitizenshipandvoiceinAfricancities.UrbanStudies.March/April2010. Bryceson,D.F.,&Potts,D.(2006).Africanurbaneconomies:Viability,vitalityorvitiation?.NewYork:PalgraveMacmillan. Carr,M.,&Chen,M.A.(2002).Globalisationandtheinformaleconomy:howglobaltradeandinvestmentimpactontheworkingpoor.InILOemploymentsectorworkingpaperontheinformaleconomy2002/1.Chen,M.,&Carr,M.(2004).Globalisation,socialexclusion,andwork:Withspecialreferencetoinformalemploymentandgender.Interna-tionalLabourReview,143,1–2. Cohen,B.(2004).Urbangrowthindevelopingcountries:Areviewofcurrenttrendsandacautionregardingexistingforecasts.WorldDevelopment,32(1),23–51. Dobler,G.(2005).South–Southbusinessrelationsinpractice:ChinesemerchantsinOshikango.Namibia,Basel:InstituteforSocialAnthro-pologyUniversityofBasel. Fafchamps,M.,Gabre-Madhin,E.,&Minten,B.(2004).Increasingreturnsandmarketefficiencyinagriculturaltrade.JournalofDevel-opmentEconomics,78(2),406–442. FOCAC(2008).ForumonChina–Africacooperation. Giddens,A.(1984).Theconstitutionofsociety.Cambridge:PolityPress.Goldstein,A.,Pinaud,N.,Reisen,H.,&Chen,X.(2006).TheriseofChinaandIndiawhat’sinitforAfrica?DevelopmentCentreStudies,DevelopmentCentreoftheOrganisationforEconomicCooperationandDevelopment. Hansen,K.T.(2004).Whorulesthestreets?ThepoliticsofvendingspaceinLusaka.InK.T.Hansen,&M.Vaa(Eds.),Reconsideringinformality:PerspectivesfromurbanAfrica.Uppsala:NordikAfrikainstitutet. Haugen,H.O.,&Carling,J.(2005).OntheedgeoftheChinesediaspora:ThesurgeofbaihuobusinessinanAfricancity.EthnicandRacialStudies,28(4),639–662. Kaplinsky,R.,Morris,M.,&Readman,J.(2002).Theglobalizationofproductmarketsandimmiserizinggrowth:lessonsfromtheSouthAfricanfurnitureindustry.WorldDevelopment,30(7),1159–1177.Kaplinsky,R.,McCormick,D.,&Morris,M.(2006).TheimpactofChinaonsub-SaharanAfrica.DepartmentforInternationalDevelopment(unpublishedreport). Kumar,K.B.,&Matsusaka,J.G.(2004).Villageversusmarketsocialcapital:anapproachtodevelopment.UniversityofSouthernCalifornia,SocialScienceResearchNetworkElectronicLibrary. Lyon,F.,&Porter,G.(2007).Marketinstitutions,trustandnorms:ExploringmoraleconomiesinNigerianfoodsystems.CambridgeJournalofEconomics.doi:10.1093/cje/bem008Accessed1.06.07. Lyons,M.,&Msoka,C.(inpress).TheWorldBankandthestreet:(How)dothedoingbusinessreformsaffectTanzania’sstreettraders.UrbanStudies. 782WORLDDEVELOPMENT Rodgers,D.(2005).YouthgangsandperverselivelihoodsstrategiesinNicaragua:Challengingcertainpreconceptionsandshiftingthefocusofanalysis,papertoArushaConference,“NewFrontiersofSocialPolicy”–Arusha. Scheld,S.(2007).The‘Chinachallenge’:activisits’responsestonewtradersinDakar,Senegal,papertotheconferenceonInformalisingEconomiesandNewOrganizingStrategiesinAfrica,NordicAfricaInstitute. Schneider,F.(2004).Thesizeoftheshadoweconomiesof145countriesallovertheworld:firstresultsovertheperiod1999to2003,IZADPNo.1431,Bonn,InstitutefortheStudyofLabour. Scoones,(1998).Sustainablelivelihoods:Aframeworkforanalysis,InstituteofDevelopmentStudies,UniversityofSussex,workingpaper72. Simone,A.(2004).Forthecityyettocome:ChangingAfricanlifeinfourcities.Durham:DukeUniversityPress. Skinner,C.(2008).StreettradeinAfrica:Areview,UniversityofKwaZuluNatal,SchoolofDevelopmentStudies,workingpaperNo.51.ISBN:978-1-86840-662-3. UNDP(2008).Makingthelawworkforeveryone,finalreport,Commis-sionforLegalEmpowermentofthePoor,NewYork. Walsham,G.,Sahay,S.(2006)Informationtechnologyfordevelopment,C2005WileyPeriodicals,Inc.PublishedonlineinWileyInterScience. WorldBank(2008).Keydevelopmentdata&statistics. Lyons,M.,Brown,A.,&Li,Z.(2008).The‘ThirdTier’ofglobalisation:AfricantradersinGuangzhou,City.OnlineAugust2008. Lyons,M.,&Snoxell,S.(2005a).Creatingurbansocialcapital:SomeevidencefrominformaltradesinNairobi.UrbanStudies,42(7),1077–1097. Lyons,M.,&Snoxell,S.(2005b).Sustainableurbanlivelihoodsandmarket-placesocialcapital:Crisisandstrategyinpettytrade.UrbanStudies,42(8),1301–1320. Maclure,R.(2006).Ididn’twanttodie,soIjoinedthem:StructurationandtheprocessofbecomingchildsoldiersinSierraLeone.JournalofTerrorismandPoliticalViolence,18(1),119–135. Morawska,E.(2004).ImmigranttransnationalentrepreneursinNewYork.InternationalJournalofEntrepreneurialBehaviourandResearch,10(5),325–343. Moser,C.(1978).Theinformalsectororpettycommodityproduction:Dualismordependenceinurbandevelopment?.WorldDevelopment,6(9).Poole,R.,Clarke,G.P.,&Clarke,D.B.(2006).CompetitionandsaturationinWestEuropeangroceryretailing.EnvironmentandPlanningA,38(11),2129–2156.doi:10.1068/a3816. ´(2009).Trafic. Porter,G.,Lyons,F.,&Potts,D.(2007).MarketinstitutionsandfoodsupplyinWestandSouthernAfrica.ProgressinDevelopmentStudies,7(2),115–134. Potts,D.(2007).Thestateandtheinformalinsub-SaharanAfricanurbaneconomies:Revisitingdebatesondualism.CrisisStatesResearchCentre,workingpaperno.18. Available online at www.sciencedirect.com 因篇幅问题不能全部显示,请点此查看更多更全内容